When.com Web Search

Search results

  1. Results From The WOW.Com Content Network
  2. Perfect competition - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Perfect_competition

    Anti-competitive regulation: It is assumed that a market of perfect competition shall provide the regulations and protections implicit in the control of and elimination of anti-competitive activity in the market place. Every participant is a price taker: No participant with market power to set prices.

  3. Market power - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Market_power

    Firms within this market structure are not price takers and compete based on product price, quality and through marketing efforts, setting individual prices for the unique differentiated products. [18] Examples of industries with monopolistic competition include restaurants, hairdressers and clothing.

  4. Market structure - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Market_structure

    Perfect competition refers to a type of market where there are many buyers and sellers that feature free barriers to entry, dealing with homogeneous products with no differentiation, where the price is fixed by the market. Individual firms are price takers [3] as the price is set by the industry as a whole. Example: Agricultural products which ...

  5. Fundamental theorems of welfare economics - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Fundamental_theorems_of...

    Barone, an associate of Pareto, proved an optimality property of perfect competition, [21] namely that – assuming exogenous prices – it maximises the monetary value of the return from productive activity, this being the sum of the values of leisure, savings, and goods for consumption, all taken in the desired proportions. [22]

  6. Lerner index - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Lerner_Index

    For L = -1/E d and E d = -1/L, the elasticity of demand for industry A will be -2.5. We can use the value of the Lerner index to calculate the marginal cost (MC) of a firm as follows: 0.4 = (10 – MC) ÷ 10 ⇒ MC = 10 − 4 = 6. The missing values for industry B are found as follows: from the E d value of -2, we find that the Lerner index is ...

  7. Price discrimination - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Price_discrimination

    Given that Market 1 has a price elasticity of demand of and Market 2 of , the optimal pricing ration in Market 1 versus Market 2 is / = [+ /] / [+ /]. The price in a perfectly competitive market will always be lower than any price under price discrimination (including in special cases like the internet connection example above, assuming that ...

  8. Monopoly price - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Monopoly_price

    In microeconomics, a monopoly price is set by a monopoly. [1] [2] A monopoly occurs when a firm lacks any viable competition and is the sole producer of the industry's product. [1] [2] Because a monopoly faces no competition, it has absolute market power and can set a price above the firm's marginal cost. [1] [2]

  9. Monopoly profit - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Monopoly_profit

    [1] [4] [2] Normally, a firm that introduces a brand new product can initially secure a monopoly for a short while. [1] [4] [2] At this stage, the initial price the consumer must pay for the product is high, and the demand for, as well as the availability of the product in the market, will be limited. As time passes, when the profitability of ...