When.com Web Search

Search results

  1. Results From The WOW.Com Content Network
  2. Marginal revenue - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Marginal_revenue

    Marginal revenue is a fundamental tool for economic decision making within a firm's setting, together with marginal cost to be considered. [ 9 ] In a perfectly competitive market, the incremental revenue generated by selling an additional unit of a good is equal to the price the firm is able to charge the buyer of the good.

  3. Inverse demand function - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Inverse_demand_function

    The marginal revenue function is the first derivative of the total revenue function or MR = 120 - Q. Note that in this linear example the MR function has the same y-intercept as the inverse demand function, the x-intercept of the MR function is one-half the value of the demand function, and the slope of the MR function is twice that of the ...

  4. Marginal rate of substitution - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Marginal_rate_of_substitution

    Under the standard assumption of neoclassical economics that goods and services are continuously divisible, the marginal rates of substitution will be the same regardless of the direction of exchange, and will correspond to the slope of an indifference curve (more precisely, to the slope multiplied by −1) passing through the consumption bundle in question, at that point: mathematically, it ...

  5. Demand - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Demand

    To compute the inverse demand equation, simply solve for P from the demand equation. [12] For example, if the demand equation is Q = 240 - 2P then the inverse demand equation would be P = 120 - .5Q, the right side of which is the inverse demand function. [13] The inverse demand function is useful in deriving the total and marginal revenue ...

  6. Roy's identity - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Roy's_identity

    Roy's identity reformulates Shephard's lemma in order to get a Marshallian demand function for an individual and a good from some indirect utility function.. The first step is to consider the trivial identity obtained by substituting the expenditure function for wealth or income in the indirect utility function (,), at a utility of :

  7. Factor shares - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Factor_shares

    So a representative agent will attempt to maximize a profit function: [2] π = m a x { K , L } F ( K , L ) ∗ P − ( r K + w L ) {\displaystyle \pi =max_{\{K,L\}}F(K,L)*P-(rK+wL)\,} where r K + w L {\displaystyle rK+wL\,} is the cost to the firm, r the rental rate of capital, w the wage rate for labor, and P is the price of the output.

  8. Exponential discounting - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Exponential_discounting

    Therefore, the preferences at t = 1 is preserved at t = 2; thus, the exponential discount function demonstrates dynamically consistent preferences over time. For its simplicity, the exponential discounting assumption is the most commonly used in economics. However, alternatives like hyperbolic discounting have more empirical support.

  9. Conditional factor demands - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Conditional_factor_demands

    Isocost v. Isoquant Graph. In the simplest mathematical formulation of this problem, two inputs are used (often labor and capital), and the optimization problem seeks to minimize the total cost (amount spent on factors of production, say labor and physical capital) subject to achieving a given level of output, as illustrated in the graph.