When.com Web Search

Search results

  1. Results From The WOW.Com Content Network
  2. Indifference curve - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Indifference_curve

    An example of how indifference curves are obtained as the level curves of a utility function. A graph of indifference curves for several utility levels of an individual consumer is called an indifference map. Points yielding different utility levels are each associated with distinct indifference curves and these indifference curves on the ...

  3. Leontief utilities - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Leontief_Utilities

    The consumer's demand is always to get the goods in constant ratios determined by the weights, i.e. the consumer demands a bundle (, …,) where is determined by the income: = / (+ +). [1] Since the Marshallian demand function of every good is increasing in income, all goods are normal goods .

  4. Normal good - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Normal_good

    A good is classified as a normal good when the income elasticity of demand is greater than zero and has a value less than one. If we look into a simple hypothetical example, the demand for apples increases by 10% for a 30% increase in income, then the income elasticity for apples would be 0.33 and hence apples are considered to be a normal good.

  5. Consumer choice - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Consumer_choice

    Depending on the indifference curves, as income increases, the quantity purchased of a good can either increase, decrease or stay the same. In the figure below, good Y is a normal good since the amount purchased increased as the budget constraint shifted from BC1 to the higher income budget constraint, BC2.

  6. Edgeworth box - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Edgeworth_box

    Whether indifference curves are primitive or derivable from utility functions; and; Whether indifference curves are convex. Assumptions are also made of a more technical nature, e.g. non-reversibility, saturation, etc. The pursuit of rigour is not always conducive to intelligibility. In this article indifference curves will be treated as primitive.

  7. Convex preferences - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Convex_preferences

    A set of convex-shaped indifference curves displays convex preferences: Given a convex indifference curve containing the set of all bundles (of two or more goods) that are all viewed as equally desired, the set of all goods bundles that are viewed as being at least as desired as those on the indifference curve is a convex set.

  8. Hicksian demand function - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Hicksian_demand_function

    The Hicksian demand function isolates the substitution effect by supposing the consumer is compensated with exactly enough extra income after the price rise to purchase some bundle on the same indifference curve. [2] If the Hicksian demand function is steeper than the Marshallian demand, the good is a normal good; otherwise, the good is inferior.

  9. Slutsky equation - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Slutsky_equation

    The substitution effect is negative as indifference curves are always downward sloping. However, the same does not apply to income effect as it depends on how consumption of a good changes with income. The income effect on a normal good is negative, so if its price decreases, the consumer's purchasing power or income increases.