When.com Web Search

Search results

  1. Results From The WOW.Com Content Network
  2. Category:Goods (economics) - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Category:Goods_(economics)

    A good in economics is any object, service or right that increases utility, directly or indirectly. A good that cannot be used by consumers directly, such as an "office building" or "capital equipment", can also be referred to as a good as an indirect source of utility through resale value or as a source of income.

  3. Exogenous and endogenous variables - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Exogenous_and_endogenous...

    In an economic model, an exogenous variable is one whose measure is determined outside the model and is imposed on the model, and an exogenous change is a change in an exogenous variable. [ 1 ] : p. 8 [ 2 ] : p. 202 [ 3 ] : p. 8 In contrast, an endogenous variable is a variable whose measure is determined by the model.

  4. Market structure - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Market_structure

    Example: Agricultural products which have many buyers and sellers, selling homogeneous goods where the price is determined by the demand and supply of the market and not individual firms. In the short run, a firm in a perfectly competitive market may gain profits or loss, but in the long run, due to the entry and exit of new firms, price will ...

  5. Homothetic preferences - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Homothetic_preferences

    In consumer theory, a consumer's preferences are called homothetic if they can be represented by a utility function which is homogeneous of degree 1. [1]: 146 For example, in an economy with two goods ,, homothetic preferences can be represented by a utility function that has the following property: for every >:

  6. Heckscher–Ohlin model - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Heckscher–Ohlin_model

    Goods that require locally abundant inputs are cheaper to produce than those goods that require locally scarce inputs. For example, a country where capital and land are abundant but labor is scarce has a comparative advantage in goods that require lots of capital and land, but little labor — such as grains.

  7. Aggregation problem - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Aggregation_problem

    An example is the abstraction of a composite good. It considers the price of one good changing proportionately to the composite good, that is, all other goods. If this assumption is violated and the agents are subject to aggregated utility functions, restrictions on the latter are necessary to yield the law of demand. The aggregation problem ...

  8. Expenditure function - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Expenditure_function

    In microeconomics, the expenditure function gives the minimum amount of money an individual needs to spend to achieve some level of utility, given a utility function and the prices of the available goods. Formally, if there is a utility function that describes preferences over n commodities, the expenditure function

  9. Bertrand paradox (economics) - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Bertrand_paradox_(economics)

    In these alternative models of oligopoly, a small number of firms earn positive profits by charging prices above cost. Suppose two firms, A and B, sell a homogeneous commodity, each with the same cost of production and distribution, so that customers choose the product solely on the basis of price. It follows that demand is infinitely price ...