When.com Web Search

Search results

  1. Results From The WOW.Com Content Network
  2. Utility functions on divisible goods - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Utility_functions_on...

    This page compares the properties of several typical utility functions of divisible goods. These functions are commonly used as examples in consumer theory . The functions are ordinal utility functions, which means that their properties are invariant under positive monotone transformation .

  3. Rivalry (economics) - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Rivalry_(economics)

    Wild fish stocks are a rivalrous good, as the amount of fish caught by one boat reduces the number of fish available to be caught by others. In economics, a good is said to be rivalrous or a rival if its consumption by one consumer prevents simultaneous consumption by other consumers, [1] or if consumption by one party reduces the ability of another party to consume it.

  4. Public good - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Public_good

    Consumers can take advantage of public goods without contributing sufficiently to their creation. This is called the free rider problem, or occasionally, the "easy rider problem". If too many consumers decide to "free-ride", private costs exceed private benefits and the incentive to provide the good or service through the market disappears.

  5. Excludability - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Excludability

    Excludability was originally proposed in 1954 by American economist Paul Samuelson where he formalised the concept now known as public goods, i.e. goods that are both non-rivalrous and non-excludable. [1] Samuelson additionally highlighted the market failure of the free-rider problem that can occur with non

  6. Free good - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Free_good

    [1] [2] [3] A free good is available in as great a quantity as desired with zero opportunity cost to society. A good that is made available at zero price is not necessarily a free good. For example, a shop might give away its stock in its promotion, but producing these goods would still have required the use of scarce resources.

  7. Samuelson condition - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Samuelson_condition

    In other words, the public good should be provided as long as the overall benefits to consumers from that good are at least as great as the cost of providing it (public goods are non-rival, so can be enjoyed by many consumers simultaneously). Supply and demand interpretation of Samuelson condition

  8. Club good - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Club_good

    Club goods (also artificially scarce goods, toll goods, collective goods or quasi-public goods) are a type of good in economics, [1] sometimes classified as a subtype of public goods that are excludable but non-rivalrous, at least until reaching a point where congestion occurs. Often these goods exhibit high excludability, but at the same time ...

  9. Common good (economics) - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Common_good_(economics)

    Normal goods are goods that experience an increase in demand as the income of consumers increases. The demand function of a normal good is downward sloping, which means there is an inverse relationship between the price and quantity demanded. [8] In other words, price elasticity of demand is negative for normal goods. Common goods mean that ...