When.com Web Search

Search results

  1. Results From The WOW.Com Content Network
  2. Inverse demand function - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Inverse_demand_function

    The marginal revenue function has twice the slope of the inverse demand function. [9] The marginal revenue function is below the inverse demand function at every positive quantity. [10] The inverse demand function can be used to derive the total and marginal revenue functions. Total revenue equals price, P, times quantity, Q, or TR = P×Q.

  3. Markup rule - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Markup_rule

    The rule also implies that, absent menu costs, a firm with market power will never choose a point on the inelastic portion of its demand curve (where and ). Intuitively, this is because starting from such a point, a reduction in quantity and the associated increase in price along the demand curve would yield both an increase in revenues ...

  4. Demand curve - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Demand_curve

    When a non-price determinant of demand changes, the curve shifts. These "other variables" are part of the demand function. They are "merely lumped into intercept term of a simple linear demand function." [14] Thus a change in a non-price determinant of demand is reflected in a change in the x-intercept causing the curve to shift along the x ...

  5. Marshallian demand function - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Marshallian_demand_function

    In microeconomics, a consumer's Marshallian demand function (named after Alfred Marshall) is the quantity they demand of a particular good as a function of its price, their income, and the prices of other goods, a more technical exposition of the standard demand function. It is a solution to the utility maximization problem of how the consumer ...

  6. Almost ideal demand system - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Almost_ideal_demand_system

    The AIDS model gives an arbitrary second-order approximation to any demand system and has many desirable qualities of demand systems. For instance it satisfies the axioms of order , aggregates over consumers without invoking parallel linear Engel curves , is consistent with budget constraints, and is simple to estimate.

  7. Lagrange inversion theorem - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Lagrange_inversion_theorem

    If the assertions about analyticity are omitted, the formula is also valid for formal power series and can be generalized in various ways: It can be formulated for functions of several variables; it can be extended to provide a ready formula for F(g(z)) for any analytic function F; and it can be generalized to the case ′ =, where the inverse ...

  8. Integrability of demand - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Integrability_of_demand

    The "integrability" in the name comes from the fact that demand functions can be shown to satisfy a system of partial differential equations in prices, and solving (integrating) this system is a crucial step in recovering the underlying utility function generating demand.

  9. Hicksian demand function - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Hicksian_demand_function

    The Hicksian demand function isolates the substitution effect by supposing the consumer is compensated with exactly enough extra income after the price rise to purchase some bundle on the same indifference curve. [2] If the Hicksian demand function is steeper than the Marshallian demand, the good is a normal good; otherwise, the good is inferior.