When.com Web Search

Search results

  1. Results From The WOW.Com Content Network
  2. Perfect competition - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Perfect_competition

    Competition reduces price and cost to the minimum of the long run average costs. At this point, price equals both the marginal cost and the average total cost for each good (P = MC = AC). The theory of perfect competition has its roots in late-19th century economic thought.

  3. Monopoly profit - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Monopoly_profit

    [2] [3] Since a competitive market has many competing firms, a customer can buy widgets from any of the competing firms. [1] [4] [2] [5] Because of this tight competition, competing firms in a market each have their own horizontal demand curve that is fixed at a single price established by market equilibrium for the entire industry as a whole.

  4. Monopoly price - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Monopoly_price

    In microeconomics, a monopoly price is set by a monopoly. [1] [2] A monopoly occurs when a firm lacks any viable competition and is the sole producer of the industry's product. [1] [2] Because a monopoly faces no competition, it has absolute market power and can set a price above the firm's marginal cost. [1] [2]

  5. Market structure - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Market_structure

    Perfect competition refers to a type of market where there are many buyers and sellers that feature free barriers to entry, dealing with homogeneous products with no differentiation, where the price is fixed by the market. Individual firms are price takers [3] as the price is set by the industry as a whole. Example: Agricultural products which ...

  6. Market power - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Market_power

    It compares a firm's price of output with its associated marginal cost where marginal cost pricing is the "socially optimal level" achieved in market with perfect competition. [41] Lerner (1934) believes that market power is the monopoly manufacturers' ability to raise prices above their marginal cost. [ 42 ]

  7. Oligopoly - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Oligopoly

    For prices above the prevailing price, the curve is relatively elastic. [60] For prices below the point, the curve is relatively inelastic. [60] The gap in the marginal revenue curve means that marginal costs can fluctuate without changing equilibrium price and quantity [57] Thus, prices tend to be rigid.

  8. Fundamental theorems of welfare economics - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Fundamental_theorems_of...

    Barone, an associate of Pareto, proved an optimality property of perfect competition, [21] namely that – assuming exogenous prices – it maximises the monetary value of the return from productive activity, this being the sum of the values of leisure, savings, and goods for consumption, all taken in the desired proportions. [22]

  9. Shutdown (economics) - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Shutdown_(economics)

    Then its variable cost function is Q 3 –5Q 2 +60Q, and its average variable cost function is (Q 3 –5Q 2 +60Q)/Q= Q 2 –5Q + 60. The slope of the average variable cost curve is the derivative of the latter, namely 2Q – 5. Equating this to zero to find the minimum gives Q = 2.5, at which level of output average variable cost is 53.75.