When.com Web Search

Search results

  1. Results From The WOW.Com Content Network
  2. Marginal cost - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Marginal_cost

    Marginal cost is the change of the total cost from an additional output [(n+1)th unit]. Therefore, (refer to "Average cost" labelled picture on the right side of the screen. Average cost. In this case, when the marginal cost of the (n+1)th unit is less than the average cost(n), the average cost (n+1) will get a smaller value than average cost(n).

  3. Cost curve - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Cost_curve

    In economics, a cost curve is a graph of the costs of production as a function of total quantity produced. In a free market economy , productively efficient firms optimize their production process by minimizing cost consistent with each possible level of production, and the result is a cost curve.

  4. Ramsey problem - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Ramsey_problem

    The Ramsey problem, or Ramsey pricing, or Ramsey–Boiteux pricing, is a second-best policy problem concerning what prices a public monopoly should charge for the various products it sells in order to maximize social welfare (the sum of producer and consumer surplus) while earning enough revenue to cover its fixed costs.

  5. Kinked demand - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Kinked_demand

    A kink in an otherwise linear demand curve. Note how marginal costs can fluctuate between MC1 and MC3 without the equilibrium quantity or price changing. The Kinked-Demand curve theory is an economic theory regarding oligopoly and monopolistic competition. Kinked demand was an initial attempt to explain sticky prices.

  6. Cost-of-production theory of value - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Cost-of-production_theory...

    In economics, the cost-of-production theory of value is the theory that the price of an object or condition is determined by the sum of the cost of the resources that went into making it. The cost can comprise any of the factors of production (including labor, capital, or land) and taxation .

  7. Marginal cost of public funds - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Marginal_cost_of_public_funds

    The applications of the marginal cost of public funds include the Samuelson condition for the optimal provision of public goods and the optimal corrective taxation of externalities in public economic theory, the determination of tax-smoothing policy rules in normative public debt analysis and social cost-benefit analysis common in practical ...

  8. Lindahl tax - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Lindahl_tax

    This equilibrium is also the efficient level of public goods, as the social marginal benefit is equivalent to the social marginal cost. [ 5 ] The importance of Lindahl equilibrium is that it fulfills the Samuelson condition and is therefore Pareto efficient , [ 3 ] despite the good in question being a public one.

  9. Economic region of production - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Economic_region_of_production

    The theory entails that there is a limit to how much one factor can be substituted for another. When production reaches a point where substitution between the factors becomes impossible (MP LK), the isoquant becomes positively sloping. No rational entrepreneur will operate at a point outside the ridge lines (Region of Economic Nonsense). [1]