When.com Web Search

Search results

  1. Results From The WOW.Com Content Network
  2. Kinked demand - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Kinked_demand

    A kink in an otherwise linear demand curve. Note how marginal costs can fluctuate between MC1 and MC3 without the equilibrium quantity or price changing. The Kinked-Demand curve theory is an economic theory regarding oligopoly and monopolistic competition. Kinked demand was an initial attempt to explain sticky prices.

  3. Market power - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Market_power

    The graph below depicts the kinked demand curve hypothesis which was proposed by Paul Sweezy who was an American economist. [29] It is important to note that this graph is a simplistic example of a kinked demand curve. Kinked Demand Curve. Oligopolistic firms are believed to operate within the confines of the kinked demand function.

  4. Demand curve - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Demand_curve

    The shift of a demand curve takes place when there is a change in any non-price determinant of demand, resulting in a new demand curve. [11] Non-price determinants of demand are those things that will cause demand to change even if prices remain the same—in other words, the things whose changes might cause a consumer to buy more or less of a ...

  5. File:Kinked demand.svg - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/File:Kinked_demand.svg

    The demand curve the oligopolist faces is that of two separate curves spliced together, creating a discontinuity in the MR curve. This means that a profit maximising firm will still produce at quantity Q and price P if marginal costs are equal to MC1, MC2 or MC3, thus explaining price stability.

  6. Income–consumption curve - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Income–consumption_curve

    In figure 3, the income–consumption curve bends back on itself as with an increase income, the consumer demands more of X 2 and less of X 1. [3] The income–consumption curve in this case is negatively sloped and the income elasticity of demand will be negative. [4] Also the price effect for X 2 is positive, while it is negative for X 1. [3]

  7. Lerner index - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Lerner_Index

    For L = -1/E d and E d = -1/L, the elasticity of demand for industry A will be -2.5. We can use the value of the Lerner index to calculate the marginal cost (MC) of a firm as follows: 0.4 = (10 – MC) ÷ 10 ⇒ MC = 10 − 4 = 6. The missing values for industry B are found as follows: from the E d value of -2, we find that the Lerner index is ...

  8. Inverse demand function - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Inverse_demand_function

    The marginal revenue function is the first derivative of the total revenue function or MR = 120 - Q. Note that in this linear example the MR function has the same y-intercept as the inverse demand function, the x-intercept of the MR function is one-half the value of the demand function, and the slope of the MR function is twice that of the ...

  9. Contract curve - Wikipedia

    en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Contract_curve

    In the case of two goods and two individuals, the contract curve can be found as follows. Here refers to the final amount of good 2 allocated to person 1, etc., and refer to the final levels of utility experienced by person 1 and person 2 respectively, refers to the level of utility that person 2 would receive from the initial allocation without trading at all, and and refer to the fixed total ...